Showing posts with label Rent Control. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Rent Control. Show all posts

Wednesday, 13 March 2024

Defending the Slumlord



 

Since landlords are getting it in the neck, again, we figured it's time to post the classic defence of the very worst of them: of the so-called "slumlord" who gouges rent, poisons tenants , and offers decent habitat only to rats and cockroaches.  Can anyone defend that? Walter Block does in this guest post ...

Defending the Slumlord

by Walter Block

"Let's see, I have a nice three-room apartment on the upper West Side … No, no Madam, not a speck of lead paint on the woodwork … it's been all chewed off."

To many people, the slumlord — alias ghetto landlord and rent gouger — is proof that man can, while still alive, attain a satanic image. Recipient of vile curses, pincushion for needle-bearing tenants with a penchant for voodoo, perceived as exploiter of the downtrodden, the slumlord is surely one of the most hated figures of the day.

The indictment is manifold: he charges unconscionably high rents; he allows his buildings to fall into disrepair; his apartments are painted with cheap lead paint, which poisons babies; and he allows junkies, rapists, and drunks to harass the tenants. The falling plaster, the overflowing garbage, the omnipresent cockroaches, the leaky plumbing, the roof cave-ins and the fires, are all integral parts of the slumlord's domain. And the only creatures who thrive in his premises are the rats.

The indictment, highly charged though it is, is spurious. The owner of "ghetto" housing differs little from any other purveyor of low-cost merchandise. In fact, he is no different from any purveyor of any kind of merchandise. They all charge as much as they can.

We all charge as much as we can


First consider the purveyors of cheap, inferior, and secondhand merchandise as a class. One thing above all else stands out about merchandise they buy and sell: it is cheaply built, inferior in quality, or secondhand. A rational person would not expect high quality, exquisite workmanship, or superior new merchandise at bargain rate prices; he would not feel outraged and cheated if bargain rate merchandise proved to have only bargain rate qualities. Our expectations from margarine are not those of butter. We are satisfied with lesser qualities from a used car than from a new car. However, when it comes to housing, especially in the urban setting, people expect, even insist upon, quality housing at bargain prices.

But what of the claim that the slumlord overcharges for his decrepit housing? This is erroneous. Everyone tries to obtain the highest price possible for what he produces, and to pay the lowest price possible for what he buys. Landlords operate this way, as do workers, minority group members, socialists, babysitters, and communal farmers. Even widows and pensioners who save their money for an emergency try to get the highest interest rates possible for their savings.

According to the reasoning that finds slumlords contemptible, all these people must also be condemned. For they "exploit" the people to whom they sell or rent their services and capital in the same way when they try to obtain the highest return possible.

But, of course, they are not contemptible — at least not because of their desire to obtain as high a return as possible from their products and services. And neither are slumlords. Landlords of dilapidated houses are singled out for something that is almost a basic part of human nature — the desire to barter and trade and to get the best possible bargain.

The critics of the slumlord fail to distinguish between the desire to charge high prices, which everyone has, and the ability to do so, which not everyone has. Slumlords are distinct, not because they want to charge high prices, but because they can. The question that is therefore central to the issue — and that critics totally disregard — is why this is so.

What usually stops people from charging inordinately high prices is the competition that arises as soon as the price and profit margin of any given product or service begins to rise. If the price of Frisbees, for example, starts to rise, established manufacturers will expand production, new entrepreneurs will enter the industry, used Frisbees will perhaps be sold in secondhand markets, etc. All these activities tend to counter the original rise in price.

If the price of rental apartments suddenly began to rise because of a sudden housing shortage, similar forces would come into play. New housing would be built by established real-estate owners and by new ones who would be drawn into the industry by the price rise. Old housing would tend to be renovated; basements, attics and sleepouts would be pressed into use. All these activities would tend to drive the price of housing down, and cure the housing shortage.

If landlords tried to raise the rents in the absence of a housing shortage, they would find it difficult to keep their apartments rented. For both old and new tenants would be tempted away by the relatively lower rents charged elsewhere.

No.  The problem is not the slumlord — the problem is a lack of competition, which means an inability to build new apartments.

Even if landlords banded together to raise rents, they would not be able to maintain the rise in the absence of a housing shortage. Such an attempt would be countered by new entrepreneurs, not party to the cartel agreement, who would rush in to meet the demand for lower priced housing. They would buy existing housing and build new housing.

Tenants would, of course, flock to the noncartel housing. Those who remained in the high-price buildings would tend to use less space, either by doubling up or by seeking less space than before. As this occurs it would become more difficult for the cartel landlords to keep their buildings fully rented.

Inevitably, the cartel would break up, as the landlords sought to find and keep tenants in the only way possible: by lowering rents. It is, therefore, specious to claim that landlords charge whatever they please. They charge whatever the market will bear, as does everyone else.

An additional reason for calling the claim unwarranted is that there is, at bottom, no really legitimate sense to the concept of overcharging. "Overcharging" can only mean "charging more than the buyer would like to pay." But since we would all really like to pay nothing for our dwelling space (or perhaps minus infinity, which would be equivalent to the landlord paying the tenant an infinite amount of money for living in his building), landlords who charge anything at all can be said to be overcharging. Everyone who sells at any price greater than zero can be said to be overcharging, because we would all like to pay nothing (or minus infinity) for what we buy.

What about a law banning slums?


Disregarding as spurious the claim that the slumlord overcharges, what of the vision of rats, garbage, falling plaster, etc.? Is the slumlord responsible for these conditions?

Although it is fashionable in the extreme to say "yes," this will not do. For the problem of slum housing is not really a problem of slums or of housing at all. It is a problem of poverty — a problem for which the landlord cannot be held responsible. And when it is not the result of poverty, it is not a social problem at all.

Slum housing with all its horrors is not a problem when the inhabitants are people who can afford higher quality housing, but prefer to live in slum housing because of the money they can save thereby.

Such a choice might not be a popular one, but other people's freely made choices that affect only them cannot be classified as a social problem. If that could be done, we would all be in danger of having our most deliberate choices, our most cherished tastes and desires characterised as "social problems" by people whose taste differs from ours.

Slum housing is a problem when the inhabitants live there of necessity — not wishing to remain there, but unable to afford anything better. Their situation is certainly distressing, but the fault does not lie with the landlord. On the contrary, he is providing a necessary service, given the poverty of the tenants.

For proof, consider a law prohibiting the existence of slums, and therefore of slumlords, without making provisions for the slum dwellers in any other way, such as providing decent housing for the poor or an adequate income to buy or rent good housing. The argument is that if the slumlord truly harms the slum dweller, then his elimination, with everything else unchanged, ought to increase the net well-being of the slum tenant.

But the law would not accomplish this. It would greatly harm not only the slumlords but the slum dwellers as well. If anything, it would harm the slum dwellers even more, for the slumlords would lose only one of perhaps many sources of income; the slum dwellers would lose their very homes.

They would be forced to rent more expensive dwelling space, with consequent decreases in the amount of money available for food, medicines, and other necessities. No. The problem is not the slumlord — the problem is poverty. Only if the slumlord were the cause of poverty could he be legitimately blamed for the evils of slum housing.

Why damn the slumlord?


Why is it then, if he is no more guilty of underhandedness than other merchants, that the slumlord has been singled out for vilification? After all, those who sell used clothes to Bowery bums are not reviled, even though their wares are inferior, the prices high, and the purchasers poor and helpless. Instead of blaming the merchants, however, we seem to know where the blame lies — in the poverty and hopeless condition of the Bowery bum.

In like manner, people do not blame the owners of junkyards for the poor condition of their wares or the dire straits of their customers. People do not blame the owners of "day-old bakeries" for the staleness of the bread. They realise, instead, that were it not for junkyards and these bakeries, poor people would be in an even worse condition than they are now in.

Although the answer can only be speculative, it would seem that there is a positive relationship between the amount of governmental interference in an economic arena, and the abuse and invective heaped upon the businessmen serving that arena. There have been few laws interfering with the "day-old bakeries" or junkyards, but many in the housing area. The link between government involvement in the housing market and the plight of the slumlord's public image should, therefore, be pinpointed.

That there is strong and varied government involvement in the housing market cannot be denied. Scatter-site housing projects, "public" housing and urban renewal projects, rental standards and zoning ordinances and building codes, are just a few examples. Each of these has created more problems than it has solved. More housing has been destroyed than created, rental housing has been withdrawn from (or not entered0 the market, racial tensions have been exacerbated, and neighbourhoods and community life have been shattered.

In each case, it seems that the spillover effects of bureaucratic red tape and bungling are visited upon the slumlord. He bears the blame for much of the overcrowding engendered by the urban renewal program. He is blamed for not keeping his buildings up to the standards set forth in unrealistic building codes that, if met, would radically worsen the situation of the slum dweller. 

Compelling "Cadillac housing" can only harm the inhabitants of "Volkswagen housing." It puts all housing out of the financial reach of the poor.

The bad incentives of rent control


Perhaps the most critical link between the government and the disrepute in which the slumlord is held is rent-control law. For rent-control legislation changes the usual profit incentives, which put the entrepreneur in the service of his customers, to incentives that make him the direct enemy of his tenant-customers.

Ordinarily the landlord (or any other businessman) earns money by serving the needs of his tenants. If he fails to meet these needs, then with enough supply in the market the tenants will tend to move out. Vacant apartments mean, of course, a loss of income. Advertising, rental agents, repairs, painting, and other conditions involved in re-renting an apartment mean extra expenditures.

In addition, the landlord who fails to meet the needs of the tenants may have to charge lower rents than he otherwise could. As in other businesses, the customer is "always right," and the merchant ignores this dictum only at his own peril.

But with rent control, the incentive system is turned around. Here the landlord can earn the greatest return not by serving his tenants well, but by mistreating them, by malingering, by refusing to make repairs, by insulting them. When the rents are legally controlled at rates below their market value, the landlord earns the greatest return not by serving his tenants, but by getting rid of them. For then he can replace them with higher-paying non-rent-controlled tenants.

If the incentive system is turned around under rent control, it is the self-selection process through which entry to the landlord "industry" is determined. The types of people attracted to an occupation are influenced by the type of work that must be done in the industry.

If the occupation calls (financially) for service to consumers, one type of landlord will be attracted. If the occupation calls (financially) for harassment of consumers, then quite a different type of landlord will be attracted. In other words, in many cases the reputation of the slumlord as cunning, avaricious, etc., might be well-deserved, but it is the rent control program in the first place that encourages people of this type to become landlords.

If the slumlord were prohibited from lording over slums, and if this prohibition were actively enforced, the welfare of the poor slum dweller would be immeasurably worsened, as we have seen. It is the prohibition of high rents by rent control and similar legislation that causes the deterioration of housing. It is the prohibition of low-quality housing by housing codes and the like that causes landlords to leave the field of housing.

The result is that tenants have fewer choices, and the choices they have are of low quality. If landlords cannot make as much profit in supplying housing to the poor as they can in other endeavors, they will leave the field. Attempts to lower rents and maintain high quality through prohibitions only lower profits and drive slumlords out of the field, leaving poor tenants immeasurably worse off.

The slumlord does make a positive contribution to society; without him, the economy would be worse off. That he continues in his thankless task, amidst all the abuse and vilification, can only be evidence of his basically heroic nature.

* * * * * 

Walter Block is an American Austrian School economist and anarcho-capitalist theorist. 
He was the Harold E. Wirth Eminent Scholar Endowed Chair in Economics at the School of Business at Loyola University New Orleans and a senior fellow of the non-profit think-tank Ludwig von Mises Institute in Auburn, Alabama.
This post is an excerpt from his 1976 book 'Defending the Undefendable [free download here]. It previously appeared at the Mises Wire.

Tuesday, 16 January 2024

Two glimpses of life for renters

 

Two glimpses here of life for renters -- one from Argentina, the other from Paris.

FIRST, in Argentina, where a 'renter's rights' law of 2020 had mandated minimum terms, improved rental standards, and rent control (with prices set by government). At the end of last year, rents were rising by around 40% and few new rentals were coming on the market.

And now? New Argentine president Javier Milei eliminated the rental restrictions and repealed the law, "and in less than a month, rents have gone down 20-30% and supply has doubled." 

Turns out that laws designed to help renters did for them just the opposite -- keeping landlords out of the market, and restricting renter choice.

MEANWHILE, in Paris, overloaded with pro-renter legislation -- making the rental market "a byzantine black box of inefficiency" -- a homeless economist wishes they'd stop trying to help. He'd like to be a renter but can't. Here's his story:

Before I turn to regulations and generalisations, let me [tell you abot myself]. I grew up outside of Paris, France. When I returned to the US at the age of 14, I promised myself I would someday return to live in the City of Lights. I have been able to return a few times a year to visit family or attend academic conferences, and I have spent some delightful summers here. But it was always temporary, and I never got to be a true Parisian and suck the cultural and culinary marrow from the city. Then, finally, it happened. For all its disruptions, COVID did leave us with at least one positive change: new attitudes to remote working and distance education. So I left a cushy endowed chair at a mediocre state university, and I found a professorship at the Universidad de las Hespérides.

The university is nominally located in the Canary Islands; it is a 100-percent-remote, start-up, classical liberal endeavor. The university was started by Gabriel Calzada, former chancellor of the classical liberal Universidad Francisco Marroquin, which has been thriving since 1971 in Guatemala City. The university aims to teach solid science that is rooted in the philosophy of freedom, through an exciting combination of synchronous and asynchronous remote classes. It’s not the comfort of an endowed chair with a reduced teaching load and a big travel budget. But I get to live in Paris, and I get to teach again, after a decade without students — I say that intentionally: in the past decade, I have had plenty of “COs” (classroom occupants) and “RGs” (revenue generators), but a student must have an actual desire to learn).

When I arrived in Paris this summer, I found the rental market to be a byzantine black box of inefficiency. I started looking in August. At the twilight of the year, I have finally — with the help of a facilitator — visited a whopping four apartments out of more than 50 inquiries, and I have been rejected by all four, because I don’t quite check the right boxes.

Why is it so difficult to secure a lease in Paris? I am a victim of strong consumer-protection laws. Any decent student in a micro-principles class can tell you that interventions have unintended consequences.

Here are some of the “protections” from which I am suffering: 
  • It is illegal to evict a tenant, even for non-payment, during the “winter truce” from November 1 to March 31. After all, it can get cold out there. 
  • An eviction procedure typically takes four to six months (aside from the five winter months, of course). After multiple steps, a landlord must seek a judge’s approval to cancel a lease and evict a tenant. The judge has one month to decide; if the judge does not grant the lease cancellation, the tenant can then get a grace period of up to three years. If the judge rules in favor of the landlord, the tenant has two months to vacate the premises (outside, again, of the five winter months). 
  • The city of Paris has enacted rent controls – these vary by neighbourhood, so there is some lip service to markets… but markets are not allowed to function. 
  • From 1997 to 2010, and again since 2023, new construction has been limited to 12 stories (37 meters or about 120 feet). From 2010 to 2013, the limit was temporarily raised to 50 meters (164 feet) for housing blocks (or about 16 stories). The urban landscape is surely more pleasant, but the opportunity cost is obvious. 
  • It will be illegal, effective in 2025, to rent any property that has the lowest environmental impact score (more than 420kwH per square meter of annual energy consumption or more than 100 kg of CO2 emissions per square meter per year). ... This means, of course: (1) a further drop in the housing stock; or (2) mandatory expenses for landlords, with an incentive to occupy one’s own property to avoid costly renovations.
There are, naturally, other causes, such as the recent rise in European interest rates (which put pressure on housing purchases, and thus on rentals), and the upcoming Paris Olympics (which offer a further incentive to buy now, so as to sublease apartments over the summer or rent them on AirBNB).

But the most interesting one is the French obsession with one’s “socioeconomic status.” Yes, France, the country of liberté, égalité, fraternité and the abolition of privileges after the Ancien Régime, slots everybody into an official socioeconomic status.
Unlike the US, where the IRS kindly taxes all forms of income (if at different rates), every French citizen has an official status: student, temporary contract, permanent contract, retired, freelance, and the like. Even though I am a dual national with France, I lack a formal status until I file to become recognised, formally, as an entrepreneur. (I wonder what Jean-Baptiste Say, who coined the word and was one of the first theorists of entrepreneurship, would say.) 
Of course, I can’t get that formal status until I have an address. So, in the meantime, my US credit score, my income, my savings, and my twelve different leases over 32 years, with a stellar history of rent payment, along with the purchase and sale of three different properties in the US — all mean nothing to a landlord or a real estate agent who can’t figure out in which box I belong. It would be much easier for me to be an impossible-to-fire French state employee with half my income.

As an economist, I tried a number of market measures, from offering a higher rent to offering a substantially bigger security deposit. This was all in vain, and I am still looking.

I’m frustrated but I’ll be fine: I have generous relatives, and I can afford hotels and AirBNBs when I need to. And, as a veteran of American public universities, I can navigate make-work bureaucracies. I pity those who lack the means or the experience, as regulations typically have regressive effects. We need only look at the sad case of San Francisco. I just wish the French government would stop helping us!


Tuesday, 10 October 2023

“In many cases, rent control appears to be the most efficient technique presently known to destroy a city except for bombing.”


Q: Bomb damage or rent control? (Answer here.)

"Rent control sounds like a good, humanitarian idea. ... Why, then, are virtually all economists opposed to rent control. Are they that hard-hearted? Well, yes. This cannot be denied. But that is not the explanation. Rather, it is due to supply and demand analysis.
    "When a price ceiling is placed below the ... point where [markets clear, i.e., ], where supply and demand curves intersect, the latter is greater than the former. That is, a shortage of the commodity or service ensues. This applies to all items bought and sold, whether it is ships and sailing wax or, more to the point, residential rental accommodation.
    "Even highly credentialled leftist economists denigrate rent control for this reason. In the view of Gunnar Myrdal: 'Rent control has in certain western countries constituted, maybe, the worst example of poor planning by governments lacking courage and vision.' According to Assar Lindbeck: 'In many cases, rent control appears to be the most efficient technique presently known to destroy a city except for bombing' ....
    "[R]ent control is like holding a tiger by the tail. It is dangerous to hold on, and even more so to let go."

~ Walter Block from his post 'With Rent Control, We Need the Courage To Do the Right Thing'

RELATED:


QUIZ: Bombing or rent control? 

Can you tell the difference? 



Thursday, 26 January 2023

"Fix housing regulation and you go along way toward fixing malinvestment."


"Most people don’t understand this process. When they see it play out, they misdiagnose what is actually going on. I see article after article claiming that [central banks like] the US Federal Reserve 'artificially' lowered interest rates, and that this created “malinvestment” into unproductive projects. They claim the problem can be fixed by raising interest rates to a level that imposes discipline on investors, a rate that doesn’t allow for low quality investments to be profitable. That’s wrong.
    "[New Zealand] does have a malinvestment problem, but it’s not at all what many pundits assume. The cause of the malinvestment is zoning and other regulations that make it difficult to build housing. And housing is not just another sector; it’s a key part of investment. These bad regulations push saving into areas that are less productive than housing construction, including marginally productive government and corporate investment.
    "The problem of malinvestment cannot be fixed [just] by having the [Reserve Bank] tweak interest rates; it requires much more fundamental solution. The only way to fix malinvestment is to remove regulations that prevent developers from building what people really want, which is high-quality housing. [Cities like Auckland were transformed in the 1920s when a ring of affordable yet attractive California bungalows were built by profit-seeking speculators at the end of new tram lines. But New Zealand has lost the ambition for such things, and settled instead for three-storey stagnation.]
    "If you ask most people what stands in the way of them having the sort of lifestyle they wish to have, not many will mention a lack of food or clothing. Most have adequate cars and TV sets. Most have a school to send their kid to and some form of health care. Instead, housing is the one area where lots of people are dissatisfied, where dramatic improvements in living standards are still possible. But that requires building new housing in locations close to good jobs. Bandaids such as rent control do not result in a single extra person having housing, and indeed reduce the housing stock in the long run. More housing is the low hanging fruit to raising living standards. Fix housing regulation and you go along way toward fixing malinvestment."
~ Scott Sumner, from his post 'Zoning and 'malinvestment'' [US references have been localised]

 

Wednesday, 25 January 2023

Warm, dry ... and increasingly out of reach

 

A lesson from Scotland for locals here who like to bash landlords in the name of improving things for renters. 

It turns out that private rents in Glasgow are rocketing as landlords, sick of being bashed by the Scottish government's many laws making it harder to be a landlord ( in the name, it's said, of improving things for renters), are simply exiting the market. CityLets, a Glasgow residential letting agency, explained that "legislation was leading to many small landlords selling up." 

The results are, predictably, disastrous for renters. Colin Macmillan, from Glasgow Property Letting, said: 

Whilst the reality of the Scottish Government’s sanctions and actions are filtering through the private rented sector, many traditional landlords have had enough and are exiting the market.
    With an oversubscription of university places, we find ourselves in a perfect storm.
    Fewer properties available with unprecedented demand equals hyper-inflated rents.
    We also find ourselves in a cost of living crisis at probably the worst time of the year, with energy costs rising as the temperature is falling, and subsequent worries that rent arrears may increase also.”
    Those involved in the rented sector said private landlords have become a 'political football'.

One of the measures that would make the the disaster even worse was a rent freeze to come in from April. In what's called "a major u-turn," the Scottish government now propose to replace it with a "cap" on rent increases. Housing minister Patrick Harvey "said the government now accepted a rent freeze would hit landlords too hard." You think?

As Natalie Solent comments

Well, “disastrous” to “bad” is an improvement. But unless and until the Scottish government realises that both rent freezes and rent caps are very nice for tenants already in place but very bad for anyone trying to rent a house or flat from the day they are announced onwards, times will be hard for those seeking to rent in Scotland.

And the same for anywhere else they're threatened.


Saturday, 17 December 2022

"The long-term consequences of rent control have long been demonstrated to be destructive to both the quality & the quantity of rental housing."


"The average voter has an understanding of economics that doesn’t extend much beyond the balance in his bank account. He has little understanding of such concepts as supply and demand, restrictions on production, land-use regulations, or price controls. To understand such concepts, one must look beyond the direct and easily identified consequences. One must look at the big picture—the full context. This includes looking at the long-term consequences.
    "The long-term consequences of rent control have long been demonstrated to be destructive to both the quality and the quantity of rental housing. Despite this overwhelming evidence, advocates of rent control believe that somehow it will be different in their city. Unable to think in principles, they believe that just because rent control has been harmful in New York City, San Francisco, and everywhere else it’s been tried doesn’t mean that it will be harmful in St. Paul, Kingston, [Auckland, Wellington, Tauranga] or any other city.
    "It is certainly understandable that renters aren’t happy about the rapidly increasing cost of housing. But the solution isn’t more restrictions on housing producers. The solution is to repeal the barriers to producing housing. For that to occur, we need a new framework for considering housing policies."
~ Texas Institute for Property Rights, from their post 'The Resurgence of Rent Control'

Wednesday, 31 March 2021

Rent Control Did to Vietnam What US Bombers Couldn't [+ QUIZ]

 

THINK HIGH RENTS ARE BAD for your city? Then wait until you see what happens under rent control. Since we're all of a sudden debating rent control as if it's a (possible) thing, it's worth reminding ourselves of Swedish economist Assar Lindbeck's observation that "in many cases rent control appears to be the most efficient technique presently known to destroy a city—except for bombing." Literally, as David Henderson reminds us in this short guest post ...

Rent Control Did to Vietnam What US Bombers Couldn't

by David R. Henderson

[Gunnar] Myrdal stated, "Rent control has in certain Western countries constituted, maybe, the worst example of poor planning by governments lacking courage and vision."

His fellow Swedish economist (and socialist) Assar Lindbeck asserted,
In many cases rent control appears to be the most efficient technique presently known to destroy a city—except for bombing.
Unfortunately, Lindbeck was wrong. Rent control is the most efficient. Case in point, South-East Asia, where rent control did to Vietnam what millions of tons of US explosives couldn't:
NEW DELHI—A “romantic conception of socialism” … destroyed Vietnam’s economy in the years after the Vietnam war, Foreign Minister Nguyen Co Thach said Friday.
    Addressing a crowded news conference in the Indian capital, Mr. Thach admitted that controls … had artificially encouraged demand and discouraged supply…. House rents had … been kept low … so all the houses in Hanoi had fallen into disrepair, said Mr. Thach.
    “The Americans couldn’t destroy Hanoi, but we have destroyed our city by very low rents. We realised it was stupid and that we must change policy,” he said.
—From a news report in the Journal of Commerce, quoted in Dan Seligman, “Keeping Up,” Fortune, February 27, 1989.

** Quotes are from Walter Block, “Rent Control,” in The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics.

** EXTRA: TAKE THIS SIMPLE QUIZ TO SEE IF YOU CAN TELL THE DIFFERENCE BETWEEN RENT CONTROL AND BOMBING.

** This post first appeared at FEE.

Monday, 30 May 2016

A housing crisis, four decades on

 

Housing crises? They’ve been with us for decades – and the answers to them are no secret. It’s not that the solutions that are in short supply, it’s the political will.

I have in front of me a book that’s been on my shelf for more than thirty years…

HCrisis

Every answer to this present housing crisis in there, and has been known for decades. You can see just from the chapter headings that that because the causes of virtually every housing crisis are political, the solutions to every housing crisis are the same:

  • Part I: The Underlying Contributing Factors

o Chapter 1: The Exclusionary Effect of Growth Controls – Bernard Frieden

o Chapter 2: Zoning & Other Land-Use Controls – Norman Karlin

o Chapter 3: The Economics of Building Codes & Standards – Peter Colwell & James Kau

o Chapter 4: Private Housing Starts & the Growth of the Money Supply – Robert Weintraub

o Chapter 5: Residential Development & the Cost of Local Public Services – Jon Sonstelle & Alan Gin

  • Part II: Land-Use Policy Responses

o Chapter 6: The Irony of ‘Inclusionary’ Zoning – Robert Ellickson

o Chapter 7: An Estimate of Residential Growth Controls’ Impact on House Prices – Lloyd Mercer & Douglas Morgan

o Chapter 8: An Economic Analysis of Zoning Laws – Carl Dahlman

o Chapter 9: The California Coastal Commissions – Economic Impacts – H. E. Frech

  • · Part III: Housing & Construction Policy Responses

o Chapter 10: Rent Controls & the Housing Crisis – Thomas Hazlett

o Chapter 11: Rent Control Voting Patterns, Popular Views, and Group Interests – Stephen DeCanio

o Chapter 12: Condominium Conversions & the ‘Housing Crisis’ – Richard Muth

o Chapter 13: Information and Residential Segregation – Perry Shapiro & Judith Roberts

  • · Part IV: The Crisis & the Legal Status of Property Rights

o Chapter 14: Property, Economic Liberties, and the Constitution of the United States – Bernard Siegan

o Chapter 15: Property Rights & a Free Society – Roger Pilon

As you can see just from the chapter headings, all the usual suspects are there: excusionary zoning driving up land costs and restricting the types and locations of new housing; gold-plated building codes protecting monopolistic suppliers;  green belts and ‘conservation estates’ that unreasonably privilige the interests of existing home-owners over would-be home-buyers; the way new money is borrowed into existence for new mortage lending; the way infrastructure planning and development has been made (by law) the province of the incompetent; the dearth of real property rights strangling any real market response to the crisis …. 

You see, all the causes of this houding crisis and virtually every other have been known about and talked about written about in detail – both the problems they cause and how to unravel them – quite literally for decades. Perhaps the only lessons that have been learned in all that time are the dire effects of racial segregation and rent controls.

The only two causes either not mentioned or not fully developed in this book are

  1. the risk-free windfall profits delivered to rental investors by the likes of the Accommodation Supplement; and
  2. the way the way new money is borrowed into existence for mortage lending – around two-thirds of all new money created in this country every year: out of thin air, and straight into second-hand housing. (But there are other books and writing that cover that.)

For what it’s worth, it looks like you can get hold of the book yourself on Amazon, or read bits of it on Google books.

And you can read what I’ve been writing on the crisis for the last twelve years at my various archives on housing, especially here, here and here – and for the last twenty years at places like this and this and this.

The solutions are neither new nor particularly complicated. They include things like replacing zoning with voluntary covenants; replacing council-controlled infrastructure with private supply and development bonds; exchanging gold-plated and nonsensical govt rules and standards and council-run inspections that place ratepayers on the hook with those agreed to and run by the insurance companies who actually take the risks; limiting (or even prohibiting altogether) the amount of new money that banks can simply borrow into existence; and of course the full and complete legal protection of all real property rights. Taken together they would make it possible once again for every builder to build affordable homes at a profit – which is the only way this crisis will eventually be resolved.

These solutions are not new. What’s needed all up is gumption – something in short supply around Molesworth St and the country’s town planning faculties. As short supply as the houses that are so desperately needed, and that their policies and rules have made all-but impossible to inexpensively provide.

A kick up the arse is the least those pricks deserve; all of them who have caused, dithered and exacerbated the situation where a whole swathe of this country is now being crucified on a cross of brick, tile, weatherboard and exclusionary zoning.

.