Showing posts with label Bill Bonner. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Bill Bonner. Show all posts

Tuesday, 10 January 2017

Trump’s Trade Catastrophe?

 

At the ‘Casey Daily Despatch’ yesterday, Bill Bonner talked about President-elect Donald Trump's apparent aversion to free trade. But as Bill explained, free trade isn't the problem… our fake money system is. Today, in this guest post he digs deeper into this serious problem…


Trade3It is worse than “voodoo economics,” says former Treasury Secretary Larry Summers. It is the “economic equivalent of creationism.”

Wait a minute…

Larry Summers is wrong about almost everything. Could he be right about this?

“Trade Cheaters”

Summers is referring to the paper written by two members of Trump’s trade team: his pick for secretary of commerce, billionaire investor Wilbur Ross, and the director of Trump’s new National Trade Council, Ph.D. economist Peter Navarro.

It calls for a turn away from free trade and toward managed trade – or what is vaguely described as “fair” trade.

Colleague Karim Rahemtulla, on an investment scouting trip in India and China, sends this note:

I met with a factory owner in China. He pays his workers 2,000 renminbi a month, about US$300. He thinks it’s too expensive and is now opening factories in Vietnam and Cambodia, where he can pay half of what he’s paying just outside Shanghai.
    In India, I saw two ads in the newspaper. One was for call centre workers with a university degree as a requirement. The pay range was between 9,000 rupees (US$132) and 15,000 rupees (US$220) a month. The other ad was for a chartered accountant with three years’ experience for the Nehru Foundation – a big Indian NGO. The pay for that was 29,000 rupees per month, about US$426.
    What kind of “fairness” is it that denies a job to a man in Calcutta to pay a man in San Jose 10 times as much for the same work?

Less than US$200 a month for a job in an Indian call center.
(Source: Karim Rahemtulla)

Ross and Navarro call China a “trade cheater.”

Imagine a town with a bar on every corner. One of these gin joints gets an idea of how to increase his customer base: Offer free drinks!

There’s a “cheater” for sure… and a moral conundrum for a nitwit.

What should a serious drinker do?

Turn up his nose… turn away his face… and take his business to another place in the name of fairness?

No. Not really.

Bad Engineers

If the new Trump administration follows the advice laid out in the Ross-Navarro plan, it will almost certainly lead to disaster.

Of course, there will probably be a disaster anyway. But as it is, you can’t fault the hotel mogul, reality TV star, and president-elect. He didn’t build this railroad; it won’t be his doing when it goes off the rails.

But Ross and Navarro are bad engineers… They’re twisting the tracks!

Specifically, they’re advising the new administration to abandon free trade in favour of crony trade – deals designed to reward or punish certain industries or countries depending on which direction the political winds and lobbyists’ money are blowing.

As far as we know, all human economic progress has been made by a combination of technological advances, specialisation, and an elaboration of the division of labour made possible by property rights, honest money, and free-market capitalism.

Anything that stands in the way of these things – for instance, crony trade deals – reduces output, wealth, and choice.

But alert readers are right: Just as free immigration can be incompatible with a zombie welfare system (it attracts immigrants who become parasites)… free trade can cause problems in a fake financial system (it causes imbalances that threaten the world economy).

Out of Hand

An honest money system has feedback loops that keep things from getting out of hand.

Under the Bretton Woods system, for instance, a nation that imported more than it exported soon found its gold reserves – and therefore its money supply – shrinking. A recession was sure to follow.

But the post-1971 fake money system has no such natural limits.

Americans bought products from overseas with the feds’ fake dollars. Foreigners – particularly the Chinese – took these dollars and used them to build out their economies… and compete with U.S. manufacturers to provide cheap products for credit-fueled U.S. consumers.

TRade4As we reported yesterday, America’s trade deficit with China (the dollar value of imports we buy from China unmatched by exports to China) now runs at $1 billion a day.

And since 1980, when trade with the Middle Kingdom really got going, we have accumulated a trade deficit of about $10 trillion with China.

That is the money that built the factories that now undercut American manufacturers… that created a $225 trillion pile of global dry debt… and that corrupted and corroded the whole world’s financial system.

Still, we wonder if Ross and Navarro really know what they are doing.

They say they aim to reduce America’s trade deficit. That is to say they want the U.S. to export more and import less… thus keeping more dollars at home.

Do they realize that our whole world economy is built on fake money, giant U.S. trade imbalances, and a mountain of debt?

Take away the trade imbalances and the whole system collapses.

The fake dollars go overseas… then come back home and buy U.S. Treasuries, lowering yields. (In the bond market, yields move “inversely” to prices.)

If the fake money stays home, Treasury yields – and the government’s borrowing costs – go up… and the whole shebang comes down. Interest rates rise. Stocks fall. The economy goes into recession… and probably depression. China is devastated. And jobs disappear everywhere… in Mexico, China… and the U.S. Is that what they really want?

Regards,


Bill Bonner is an American author of books and articles on economic and financial subjects, the founder and president of Agora Publishing, co-founder and regular contributor to The Daily Reckoning, and author of a daily financial column,Diary of a Rogue Economist.
    He is author and co-author of Financial Reckoning Day: Surviving The Soft Depression of The 21st Century; Empire of DebtMobs, Messiahs and Markets and the recent Hormegeddon: How Too Much of a Good Thing Leads to Disaster.
    This post originally appeared at the Casey Daily Despatch.

 

RELATED POSTS:

.

Monday, 29 February 2016

The Fed's phony boom is becoming a real bust

Guest post by Bill Bonner, Editor, The Bill Bonner Letter

Editor's Note: All along, we’ve known the Federal Reserve's actions to "goose" the economy would cause a financial disaster. Although these actions created a “fake” recovery from the 2008 financial crisis, they’ve set us up for an even worse collapse today, says Bill Bonner in this guest post. Right now, it's all starting to fall apart - and this bust is just getting started...

[Bill originally wrote this essay on January 18, 2016, in Bill Bonner’s Diary.]


The Fed's Phony Boom Is Becoming a Real Bust
by Bill Bonner

The average stock in the S&P 1500—which includes about 90% of all stocks listed in the U.S.—is now down more than 15% from its June 2015 high. The standard definition of a bear market is a sustained fall of 20% or more from recent highs.

"Woeful earnings," suggested MarketWatch as a cause.

Another guess: "The stock market is freaking out over Trump and Sanders."

Barron's was closer to the real source of the plunge: "Without Fed's Juice, Market Suffers Withdrawal Pains."

In 1971, phony fiat money replaced the old gold-backed dollar...and money that came "out of nothing" replaced real savings.

At first, inflation rates rose. No one trusted the new fiat dollar. But then, incoming Fed chairman Paul Volcker showed the world that the U.S. could manage its currency in a responsible way.

Consumer-price inflation fell, along with interest rates. Debt increased. And gradually, every Middlesex village and farm became dependent on more and more bank credit. Bank credit, not real savings, is what generates prosperity said the mandarins.

Instead, bubbles just kept bursting: the dot-com bubble blew up in 2000. The mortgage finance bubble blew up in 2007.

Now, it looks as though another bubble is deflating...

Booze Binge

In 2008, the Fed cut rates all the way down to the "zero bound" to try to keep the jig going.

But after seven years of its emergency zero-interest-rate policy (ZIRP), it became obvious that something had to be done to get back to "normal."

Like a long binge on booze and drugs, things were starting to get a little weird.

The juice had to go.

But we doubt that the syringes and the Johnnie Walker have been put away for long. Despite announcing a great improvement in employment, for example, there have never been so many American men without jobs.

Retail sales are falling. The transport industry—ships, trucks, rails—is in a funk. And the energy sector is in crisis...with as much as one-third of the sector's debt headed for default.

What's the matter?

The simple answer is that credit is not expanding fast enough. Lenders have become wary. Rolling over short-term financing is getting harder and harder to do.

Yields on supposedly "risk-free" Treasury bonds are going down (and prices are going up). Yields on junk bonds are going up (and prices are going down).

"Any time credit fails to increase by at least 2% a year," said credit analyst Richard Duncan at Macro Watch, "the economy shrinks."

From Boom to Bust

And what's happening now? How fast is credit increasing?

Uh-oh...

It's not increasing at all. It's falling...for the first time since 2009.

Not only is the juice no longer going into the system, it is actually going out.

Which is just what you'd expect. The phony boom created and funded with the Fed's phony money (counterfeit capital that is simply borrowed into existence) is now turning into a real bust.

China's foreign exchange reserves are falling. The ships sit idle in their ports. Orders for new trucks, new rail cars, new tankers, and yellow machines of all sorts are hitting record lows.

The whole kit and caboodle creaks and groans to a halt.

And now, Bloomberg asks: "Is it over?"

At least that question is easy to answer. No, it's not over. It has hardly even begun.

Regards,

Bill

Thursday, 5 March 2015

A Bearish Nightmare…

Guest post by Bill Bonner

Rubber_band_walletDear Diary,

US stocks fell yesterday. The Dow dropped 85 points, or 0.5%. No biggie.

The biggie is still ahead…

Our guess is the smart money is selling to the dumb money. The people who take the trouble to figure out what something is really worth are unloading. People who just think they should be “in the stock market” are buying.

The “big three” US stock market benchmarks – the S&P 500, the Dow and the Nasdaq – are at near record levels.

Why? Because they represent good value for money? Or because they are propped up by near-zero interest rates and a flood of QE liquidity, now coming from Japan and Europe?

Don’t forget: Global growth is slowing. US corporate earnings are falling. Europe is in danger of coming unstuck in June, when the Greeks have to face up to making a big payment on their debt. And China looks more and more like a massive case of malinvestment on the verge of going bad.

A Time for Modesty

Economic researcher Chris Martenson recently interviewed former investment banker and broker Grant Williams of the Things That Make You Go Hmmm blog for some insight:

We don’t know how it will end, but something has to give. It’s a question of what it will be. Because when you start playing with the forces of nature, you can suppress them for a while, but they will eventually overwhelm you. We’ve seen this constantly throughout history.
   
Stocks can… and will… fall. They always do.

And newsletter veteran Richard Russell, of Dow Theory Letters, gives more detail:

Many an investor will be wiped out if he insists on waiting to find out if the bull market has topped out in hindsight. The way around this is to limit yourself to conservative positions in the market.
   
The bearish nightmare could be as follows: One day the market opens with the Dow gapping down 1,000 points. The exchange decides to close for three days. Bearish rumours and fantasies flood the media.
   
With the market closed, there is no liquidity, and stockholders are locked into positions that are unknown in terms of what their positions are worth. Fear takes over, and when the market opens again, it gaps down in an erratic series of crashes.
   
This is a bearish scenario but one that has occurred to me. It also makes the case for subscribers holding very conservative positions in stocks or ETFs. This is not a time for genius. It’s a time for modesty, small or no positions in stocks, and peace of mind.

When the crash comes, everybody rushes for the door. The sellers are all there. But where are the buyers?

They disappear.

The other thing that disappears is credit… then cash.

The Fed Is Not “Printing Money”

One of the great mysteries of the post-crisis world is why consumer prices have failed to take off. After all, the Fed was “printing money” by the trillions.

According to classic theory, a larger volume of money should lead to higher consumer prices.

It took a long time for us to figure it out: The Fed is not “printing money” at all. It is lowering the cost of credit.

ZIRP (zero-interest-rate policy) and QE (quantitative easing) accomplish the same thing by different means. They make credit – and speculation – cheaper by lowering borrowing costs [and producing counterfeit capital].

Since 1971, cash and credit have been indistinguishable. You can buy a steak dinner with a credit card or with cash. And as long as credit continues to expand, your credit card will be as good as cash.

Adding credit to the system, rather than cash, is how Wall Street got rich. It sold credit!

And it is why the rich got richer, too: They were creditworthy! They could take the Fed’s cheap credit and bid for stocks and bonds – driving up asset prices.

All the plain people could do was to borrow money to buy a car or, if they couldn’t find a job, get a student loan.

They could go deeper into debt. But they couldn’t benefit from the rise in asset prices – because they didn’t have any assets. The top 5% of the population owns 75% of financial assets. The bottom 80% owns less than 5%.

Free Fall

But there’s one big difference between cash and credit: In a crisis, credit collapses.

Cash – even cash backed by nothing – nevertheless has a physical, tangible presence. If the stock market gets cut in half, those Jacksons and Lincolns are still there. You can still use them to buy beer and cigarettes.

But what happens in a real credit crisis? What happened in 2008? Every bank on Wall Street would have gone broke had the feds not intervened so vigorously.

Credit works on trust. A friend had a huge line of credit at Lehman Brothers in 2008. In 2009 he was out of business; his credit had vanished.

Now, imagine the next crisis. We’ve already seen what happened to dot-coms, housing and energy. What would happen if all asset classes were affected at once?

The collateral of the banking industry would fall. The banks would look at each other and wonder whose credit was still good. Merchants would look at your credit card and wonder if its issuer was still in business. House sellers would check your mortgage company to see if it was still solvent.

Trust would disappear. And along with it, credit. The economy would go into free fall.

Then the big surprise: Instead of the inflation or hyperinflation that we expected, suddenly the dollar – the almighty dollar… the old-fashioned, paper, greenback buck – would become more valuable.

That is not the end of the story. It is just the beginning.

Stay tuned…
Regards,
Bill


imageBill Bonner is an American author of books and articles on economic and financial subjects, the founder and president of Agora Publishing, co-founder and regular contributor to The Daily Reckoning, and author of a daily financial column,Diary of a Rogue Economist.
    He is author and co-author of Financial Reckoning Day: Surviving The Soft Depression of The 21st Century; Empire of DebtMobs, Messiahs and Markets and the recent Hormegeddon: How Too Much of a Good Thing Leads to Disaster.
This article originally appeared at at Bill's website.
Pic: Wikimedia

Friday, 10 October 2014

We’re in an Economic Neverland - Part 2

Guest post by Bill Bonner, continued from yesterday (check out part one here).

Yesterday, Bill Bonner looked at some of the destructive effects of Zero or Negative Interest Rate Policy (ZIRP or NIRP), and the issuing of all that new debt . Today he continues …

Neverland - Part 2

"There can be nothing more unreal in
its pretensions than debt currency itself."
Charles Holt Carroll (1860)

Ex Nihilo Nihil Fit

I spent much of the spring at our ranch in Argentina. I was cut off from the flow of news and opinion. No telephone. No TV or radio. But I was still thinking… in a desultory way… about how you can get something from nothing.

“Out of nothing comes nothing,” is the expression. It expresses a deep truth, much like the law of conservation of matter and energy. You can’t get something from nothing. You can’t get rid of something once you’ve gotten it, either. That is, you can’t get nothing from something. As you know, the law of conservation of matter and energy tells us that you can just change the way it is expressed… where and how it shows up.

Getting something out of nothing violates the laws of the universe. It doesn’t seem possible. And of course, it’s not. Free money is oxymoronic. Like an “honest dollar” or a “reclusive film star,” it doesn’t exist.

So, if you think this free money coming from the Fed has no cost, you’re probably going to be surprised… and disappointed. The bill for it is out there somewhere. In the future. Debt is essentially a financial arrangement between the past and the future. And eventually, the future comes.

I was thinking about this when I was helping with the roundup at our ranch in Argentina. At the time, I couldn’t figure it out. How can you get something from nothing? Who gets the bill? How? When?

Then a 2,000-pound bull charged me.

Thursday, 9 October 2014

We’re in an Economic Neverland

In a world of virtually free money – the money of near-Zero or even Negative Interest Rates excreted by central banks – the clear-eyed man could be king. But not if the well-connected man has blinded him first, says Bill Bonner in this guest post.

We’re in an Economic Neverland, Part 1

Anything is possible in a NIRP (negative-interest-rate policy) world.

When central banks are resorting to negative interest rates, as the ECB did recently, everything goes topsy-turvy. A trillion dollars here… a trillion there. Pretty soon we’re talking about the end of the world as we have known it.

In the US, in the first seven decades of the 20th century, the relationship between debt and GDP was fairly stable. Debt was at about 150% of output. Then Nixon severed the link with gold in 1971… and debt grew even faster than GDP. Right now, the ratio of debt to GDP is 370%.

By my calculations, the excess over what is needed to generate growth in the post-war years is about $33 trillion. Annual US GDP is about $17 trillion. At 150% of output, we’d have debt of about $26 trillion. Instead, it’s $59 trillion. We’d have $33 trillion less debt, in other words, if we’d stuck to the 150% ratio.

An Explosion in Debt

The central question we asked at the recent Global Partners’ Reunion in France was: Why didn’t we stick to the old ratio? And where does all the explosion in new debt lead?

imageIn my opening address to the group, I named the place we find ourselves “Neverland,” like Michael Jackson’s ranch in California. It’s a place where anything can happen… and something bad always does.

For example, Elizabeth and I were recently wondering if we should upgrade some apartments we own. What if we spend $50,000 on each of them? How much more in rent would we have to get to make the investment worthwhile?

The answer is it depends on the cost of capital. If it costs you 4% a year to borrow money, you’d need a return somewhere in excess of $2,000 a year—or about $170 a month—to make the improvements pay off.

These are dumpy apartments—renting for about $800 a month each. But it’s a good area. Up and coming, apparently. Putting $50,000 into each one would mean a total investment in the building of about $400,000. And there would be a loss of income while the work was going on.

Still… the investment seemed worthwhile, largely because we wouldn’t have such a dumpy place next door to our house. But the key question is always: What is the real cost of capital? It makes financial sense only if your return on investment is greater than your cost of money. That’s why this is probably the single most important question in a capitalist economy.

The interest rate is often called “the hurdle rate.” Because, if the return on your investment can’t jump the hurdle, it means it’s not a good idea. Instead of adding to the wealth of the human race, it subtracts from it. Net result: a loss of capital. If you don’t know what the hurdle rate really is, you are likely to do a lot of dumb things… and likely to get poorer as a result.

What is the real cost of capital now? What’s the hurdle rate? Does anyone know?

Things Aren’t What They Seem

Wednesday, 20 August 2014

In the Hands of Economists, the More Precise the Number, the Bigger the Lie.

In this second-part of the excerpt we started yesterday, author of three best-selling books already, Bill Bonner eviscerates what passes for modern economics in this excerpt from ‘Hormageddon: How Too Much of a Good Thing Leads to Disaster.’

Excerpt #2 from Hormageddon: How Too Much of a Good Thing Leads to Disaster
By Bill Bonner

The Original Economists

There was a time when economists were not so conceited, not so bold and arrogant, not so ambitious… and not such dumbbells. The original practitioners of the trade saw themselves as natural or moral philosophers.

It was ‘moral’ in the sense that when you make a mistake you have to pay for it. You don’t watch where you’re going and you step on a rake, the handle comes up and hits you in the face. You go away on a trip and forget to pay the electric bill, you come home and the lights don’t work. There is no complex mathematics that will bring the lights back on. There are no abstract theories—such as countercyclical fiscal policies—that will do it either. The solution is simple: you have to pay the bill. You have to suffer the consequences of your own mistake to set it straight. That’s moral philosophy.

But when your washing machine breaks down, you turn it off and try to fix it. This is a mechanical—not moral—system, and not a particularly complex one at that. Sometimes even a few whacks with a hammer and some choice swear words can work wonders. Percussive maintenance works!

The trouble is, economies are not washing machines. They are complex, moral systems. An economic system requires a deft, nuanced touch. But economists come up with theories and ‘fixes’ that are as clumsy as a wrench and as blunt as a hammer. They almost always lead to trouble.

The Ur-economists of old knew better. They observed animals and nature and tried to draw out the laws and principles that helped understand them. Same thing for man and his natural economy. They watched. They reflected. They attempted to make sense of it in the same way a naturalist makes sense of a beehive or an ant colony. ‘How does it work?’ they asked themselves.

In the 18th and 19th century, they were able to formulate “laws” which they believed described the way a human economy functioned.

The Wealth of Nations was Adam Smith’s observation about how wealth was created. How did people know what to produce? How did they know what price to sell it at? How did they know when to shift to other things, or when to increase production? He saw individuals guided by an ‘invisible hand’ that led them to follow their own interests and thereby respond to the needs and desires of others.

Later, other economists focused on prices. Prices had an information content that was essential for everyone, that allowed producers and consumers to get on the same page. These economists understood that when you manipulate the numbers you confuse them both.

Among the other phenomena that these proto-economists discovered were Say’s Law and Gresham’s Law.

French businessman and economist, Jean-Baptiste Say, discovered that “products are paid for with products,” not merely with money. He meant that you needed to produce things to buy things; you could not just produce money… has anyone ever mentioned this to the Federal Reserve?

Long before Say, a 16th century English financier named Sir Thomas Gresham noticed that if people had good money and bad money of equal purchasing power, they’d spend the bad money and hoard the good money.

Economists were like astronomers. When they discovered something new they named it after themselves. They were just observers back then and they needed some reward. No one hired them to ‘run’ an economy or to ‘improve’ one. They would have thought the idea absurd. How could they know what people wanted? How could a single person, or a single generation, improve an infinitely complex system that had evolved over thousands of years?

Central planners can rig the economy to produce anything—tanks, education, bridges, bureaucrats, assassinations, you name it. But none of these things are priced in the open market, the way the original economists observed them at the birth of their discipline. These machinations are exceedingly annoying to the invisible hand. The reason is that it needs to see what things are really worth to us or it cannot properly allocate capital and guide consumers. Things that are not priced by willing buyers and sellers are like dark matter in the economic universe. They provide no light, no clarity, nothing that can help consumers, taxpayers, or investors decide what to do with their money. Many of the products and services commanded or provided by non-market entities are probably worthless; or worse, actually of negative value. That’s when the invisible hands starts drinking early.

By the Numbers

What is the meaning of life? In the Hitchhiker’s Guide to the Galaxy, Arthur Dent searches the interplanetary system for the answer. Finally, he finds a computer, Deep Thought, that tells him: “Forty-two.”

Wouldn’t it be nice if meaning could be digitized? Unfortunately for the deep thinkers in the economics profession, the important things in life involve qualitative judgments. Understanding them requires analogue thinking, not digital calculations.

Numbers are a good thing. Economics is full of numbers. It is perfectly natural to use numbers to count, to weigh, to study and compare. They make it easier and more precise to describe quantities. Instead of saying I drank a bucket of beer you say, I drank two 40s. Then instead of saying ‘I threw up all over the place,’ you say, I threw up on an area 4 feet square.

But in economics we reach the point of diminishing returns with numbers very quickly. They gradually become useless. Later, when they are used to disguise, pervert and manipulate, they become disastrous. Hormegeddon by the numbers. Ask Deep Thought the meaning of life then and the answer is likely to be “Negative Forty-Two.”

Exactly what point does the payoff from numbers in the economics trade become a nuisance? Probably as soon as you see a decimal point or a Greek symbol. I’m not above eponymous vanity either. So I give you Bonner’s Law:

In the hands of economists, the more precise the number, the bigger the lie.

For an economist, numbers are a gift from the heavens. They turn them, they twist them, they use them to lever up and screw down. They also use them to scam the public. Numbers help put nonsense on stilts.

Numbers appear precise, scientific, and accurate. By comparison, words are sloppy, vague, subject to misinterpretation. But words are much better suited to the economist’s trade. The original economists understood this. Just look at Wealth of Nations—there are a lot of words in that thing. After all, we understand the world by analogy, not by digits. Besides, the digits used by modern economists are most always fraudulent.

“Math makes a research paper look solid, but the real science lies not in math but in trying one’s utmost to understand the real workings of the world,” says Professor Kimmo Eriksson of Sweden’s Malardalen University.

He decided to find out what effect complicated math had on research papers. So, he handed out two abstracts of research papers to 200 people with graduate degrees in various fields. One of the abstracts contained a mathematical formula taken from an unrelated paper, with no relevance whatever to the matter being discussed. Nevertheless, the abstract with the absurd mathematics was judged most impressive by participants. Not surprisingly, the further from math or science the person’s own training, the more likely he was to find the math impressive.

This is from a research paper paid for by the Federal Reserve. It purports to tell us that when a house next door to you sells at an extremely low firesale price, your house gets marked down too:

This motivates estimation of the following linear probability model:

I attempted to put in another illustration, a model in which economists believe they calculate the effect of large-scale asset purchases by the Fed (aka Quantitative Easing), but my trusty laptop computer rebelled. It wouldn’t copy the formula. The ‘clipboard’ wasn’t big enough, or so it claimed at least. I suspect the real reason was moral and political indignation was; a laptop knows a digital fraud when it sees one.

Without coming to any conclusion about how good these formulae actually are, let us look at some of their components. Whereas the classical economist—before Keynes and econometrics—was a patient onlooker; the modern, post-Keynes economist has had ants in his pants. He has not the patience to watch his flock, like a preacher keeping an eye on a group of sinners, or a botanist watching plants. Instead, he comes to the jobsite like a construction foreman, hardhat in hand ready to open his tool chest immediately; to take out his numbers.

Measuring Quantity vs. Quality

If you are going to improve something you must be able to measure it. Otherwise how do you know that you have made an improvement? But that is the problem right there. How do you measure improvement? How do you know that something is ‘better?’ You can’t know. ‘Better’ is a feature of quality. It can be felt. It can be sensed. It can be appreciated or ignored. But it can’t actually be measured.

What can be measured is quantity. And for that, you need numbers. But when we look carefully at the basic numbers used by economists, we first find that they are fishy. Later, we realize that they are downright fraudulent. These numbers claim to have meaning. They claim to be specific and precise. They are the basis of weighty decisions and far-reaching policies that pretend to make things better. They are the evidence and the proof that led to thousands of Ph.D awards, thousands of grants, scholarships and academic tenure decisions. More than a few Nobel Prize winners also trace their success to the numbers arrived at on the right side of the equal sign.

1… 2… 3… 4… 5… 6… 7… 8… 9…

There are only 9 cardinal numbers. The rest are derivative or aggregates. These numbers are useful. In the hands of ordinary people they mean something. ‘Three tomatoes’ is different from ‘five tomatoes.’

In the hands of scientists and engineers, numbers are indispensable. Precise calculations allow them to send a spacecraft to Mars and then drive around on the Red Planet.

But a useful tool for one profession may be a danger in the hands of another. Put a hairdresser at the controls of a 747, or let a pilot cook your canard à l’orange, and you’re asking for trouble. So too, when an economist gets fancy with numbers, the results can be catastrophic.

On October 19, 1987, for example, the bottom dropped out of the stock market. The Dow went down 23%. “Black Monday,” as it came to be called, was the largest single-day drop in stock market history.

The cause of the collapse was quickly traced to an innovation in the investment world called “portfolio insurance.” The idea was that if quantitative analysts—called ‘quants’—could accurately calculate the odds of a stock market pullback, you could sell insurance—very profitably—to protect against it. This involved selling index futures short while buying the underlying equities. If the market fell, the index futures would make money, offsetting the losses on stock prices.

The dominant mathematical pricing guide at the time was the Black-Scholes model, named after Fischer Black and Myron Scholes, who described it in a 1973 paper, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities.” Later, Robert C. Merton added some detail and he and Scholes won a Nobel Prize in 1997 for their work. (Black died in 1995.)

Was the model useful? It was certainly useful at getting investors to put money into the stock market and mathematically-driven hedge funds. Did it work? Not exactly. Not only did it fail to protect investors in the crash of ‘87, it held that such an equity collapse was impossible. According to the model, it wouldn’t happen in the life the universe. That it happened only a few years after the model became widely used on Wall Street was more than a coincidence. Analysts believe the hedging strategy of the funds who followed the model most closely—selling short index futures—actually caused the sharp sell-off.

“Beware of geeks bearing formulas,” said Warren Buffet in 2009.

Indeed.


Bill Bonner is an American author of books and articles on economic and financial subjects, the founder and president of Agora Publishing, co-founder and regular contributor to The Daily Reckoning, and author of a daily financial column, Diary of a Rogue Economist.

He is author and co-author of Financial Reckoning Day: Surviving The Soft Depression of The 21st Century, Empire of Debt and Mobs, Messiahs and Markets.

Click here to order Bill Bonner’s forthcoming book: Hormegeddon: How Too Much of a Good Thing Leads to Disaster.

This excerpt, and Part One that appeared yesterday, first appeared at the Casey Daily Despatch.

Tuesday, 19 August 2014

How Too Much of a Good Thing Leads to Disaster

Author of three best-selling books, in this excerpt from his forthcoming, and fourth, our guest poster Bill Bonner eviscerates what passes for modern economics.

Excerpt from Hormegeddon: How Too Much of a Good Thing Leads to Disaster
By Bill Bonner

Prepare for Hormogeddon

This book has a modest ambition: to catch a faint glimmer of truth, perhaps out of the corner of our eye. What truth? It is a phenomenon I call Hormegeddon.

German pharmacologist Hugo Schulz first described its scientific antecedent in 1888. He put small doses of lethal poison onto yeast and found that it actually stimulated growth. Various researchers and bio-chemical tinkerers also experimented with it in subsequent years and came to similar findings.

Finally, in 1943, two scientists published a journal article about this phenomenon and gave it a name: “hormesis.” It is what happens when a small dose of something produces a favorable result, but if you increase the dosage, the results are a disaster. Giving credit where it is due, Nassim Taleb suggested applying the term beyond pharmacology in his 2012 book, Antifragile.

Disasters come in many forms. Epidemic disease is a disaster. A fire can be a disaster. A hurricane, an earthquake, a tornado. All these natural phenomena are the disastrous versions of normal, healthy environmental processes. But this book is about another kind of natural disaster. Public-policy disasters.

Generally speaking, public-policy disasters are what you get when you apply rational, small-scale problem-solving logic to an inappropriately broad situation. First, you get a declining rate of return on your investment (of time or resources). Then, if you keep going – and you always keep going – you get a disaster.

The problem is, these disasters cannot be stopped by well-informed, smart people with good intentions, because those exact people are the ones who cause these disasters in the first place.

“Hormegeddon” is my shorthand way of describing what happens when you have too much of a good thing in a public-policy context…

Chapter Two: Too Much Economics

“Can you by legislation add one farthing to the wealth of the country? You may, by legislation, in
one evening, destroy the fruits and accumulations of a century of labour; but I defy you to show
me how, by the legislation of this House, you can add one farthing to the wealth of the country.”
—Richard Cobden

Friedrich Hayek made the point on numerous occasions that the more a person has been educated, the greater the likelihood he is an idiot. That insight may or may not be true of those who spent their school years in engineering and science; it is certainly true for those who have studied economics. The more they have learned, the dumber they get. Like a cloud rising against a mountain, when a young person enters the economics department, the higher up the academic slope he goes, the more the common sense rains out of him.

The trouble with The Economist, The Financial Times, the US government and most mainstream economists is not that they don’t know what is going on, but that they don’t want to know. It would be counterproductive. Nobody gets elected by promising to do nothing. Nobody [since Friedrich Hayek] gets a Nobel Prize for letting the chips fall where they may. Nobody attracts readers or speaking fees by telling the world there is nothing that can be done. Instead, they meddle. They plan. They tinker. Usually, the economy is robust enough to thrive despite their efforts. But not always.

From 2007-2012, Nobel Prize winning economists Paul Krugman and Joseph Stiglitz, along with celebrity economist, Jeffrey Sachs, and practically all their colleagues, failed to notice the most important happening in their field. This in itself was not news. Not noticing things came easily to them, like second nature. In fact, you might say they built their careers on not noticing things.

Blindness was part of their professional training. It was what allowed them to win coveted prizes and key posts in a very competitive occupation. Had they been more reflective, or more observant, they would probably be teaching at a community college.

Their obstinate dedication to being unaware marks the culmination of a long trend in economics. By the late 20th century, leading economists preferred not to look. They closed their eyes to what an economy actually is (to how it works) and focused on their own world—a make-believe playground of numbers, theories and public information, with little connection to the world that most people lived in.

Irving Fisher, one of the greatest economists of the 20th century, on September 5, 1929: “There may be a recession in stock prices, but not anything in the nature of a crash.”

Julius Barnes, head of Hoover’s National Business Survey Conference, announced in 1930: “The spring of 1930 marks the end of a period of grave concern. American business is steadily coming back to a normal level of prosperity.”

And now, in the 21st century, more than 75 years later, economists are up to more mischief. And part of the mischief involves not noticing things that are under their noses, including the fact that their discipline is 90% claptrap.

Minutes of the Federal Reserve’s Open Market Committee meetings, released in 2013, showed that neither Ben Bernanke, the Fed chairman, nor other key decisions makers had any idea what was coming their way in 2007.

“My forecast for the most likely outcome over the next few years,” opined Fed governor, Donald Kohn, “is…growth a little below potential for a few quarters, held down by the housing correction, and the unemployment rate rising a little further.”

Ben Bernanke set the pace for his fellow Fed officials back in 2005, with a stunning display of arrogance and ignorance about the threat derivatives posed to the global financial system:

“they are traded among very sophisticated financial institutions and individuals who have considerable incentive to understand them and to use them properly. The Federal Reserve’s responsibility is to make sure that the institutions it regulates have good systems and good procedures for ensuring that their derivatives portfolios are well managed and do not create excessive risk…”

Then, two years later, he was at it again:

“At this juncture…the impact on the broader economy and the financial markets of the problems in the subprime markets seems likely to be contained…”

Again, in 2008: Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were “adequately capitalised,” he said. They were “in no danger of failing.”

In the financial pile-up of ‘08-’09, derivatives did, in fact, create so much risk that the system couldn’t handle it. Subprime crashed. Almost every financial school bus was dented. And practically all of Wall Street—Fannie and Freddie too—had to be towed away.

And then, in 2013, Ben Bernanke, as blind to the approaching financial disaster as a pick-up truck to a brick wall, was driving the whole world economy.

That economists are incompetent hardly needs additional evidence or argument. But they are far from being idiots. On the contrary, they are too clever by half. They are such able swindlers and accomplished charlatans that they convince themselves of things that couldn’t possibly be true. They do so for reasons of professional vanity…and for money.

Ben Bernanke’s ridiculousness was not the exception to the rule. It was the rule. He was following a hallowed tradition.

These economists made themselves into useful stooges by creating a simpleton’s model of the economy. For simplicity’s sake, I will refer to this model as the Simpleton’s Economic Model, or ‘SEM’ for short. So stripped down, shorn of all nuance and ambiguity, that it bears no relationship or resemblance to a real economy. It is like a stick figure that is meant to represent a real human being.

Still, SEM is something economists can work with. It brings them PhDs and Nobel prizes. It makes people think they know what they are talking about. It both justifies and permits naïve meddling—like a surgeon whose only training comes from studying stick-figure diagrams.

At its most basic level, SEM requires that complex economic transactions be reduced to numbers and statistics. This alone is fraudulent, as we will see. Then, based on these numbers economists are able to do math—the more complex the better—to arrive at results that are internally coherent but describe life in a parallel, artificial and unreal economic universe. The SEM begins with a statistical construct—the average man—who doesn’t exist (nor has ever existed) in reality. There is a simple example that illustrates how hollow this construct truly is:

Imagine Warren Buffett moves to a city with 50,000 starving, penniless beggars. This is what economists would say about that city: “Stop whining…the average person in the city is a millionaire.”

Statistically speaking, the economist would be correct, but ultimately be peddling a form of information with negative content. After you heard it you would actually know less than you knew before. This, by itself, is destructive enough, but it’s what happens next that is the real problem.

On the foundation of fraudulent numbers and empty statistics like these, economists build a whole, elaborate tower of hollow, meaningless facts and indicators: the unemployment rate, consumer price inflation, the GDP. None are ‘hard’ numbers, yet the economist uses them as a rogue policeman uses his billy club…to beat up on honest citizens.

Economists, with their scammy numbers and slimy theories, are an important element of central planning, an essential ingredient for hormegeddon.

Ain’t No Average Man

Unlike a real, hard science, you can never prove economic hypotheses wrong. There are too many variables, including the most varied variable of all—man. He will do one thing sometimes, another thing the next time, then something else the time after that. Sometimes he seems to respond to economic incentives. Sometimes he’s out to lunch. Why? Because every man is different. Unique. Infinitely complex. And thus, ultimately unknowable.

The problem with this is that you can’t do much central planning in an economy where all the key component parts are unique and unknowable. You’d have to strip them of their particularities, reducing them to a simpler figure that you can work with—the average man. This ‘average man’ bears no resemblance to a real man. But he is useful to the economics profession. He is predictable, whereas real men are not. He will do their bidding; real men will not. He is like an interchangeable part in a vast machine, a cog; again, real men are not that way.

You turn a man into a stick figure with numbers. You say that he has 2.2 children. Or that he earns $42,500. Or, that he is 7.8% unemployed. None of it is true. It is all a convenient fabrication.

If you could get man to do what you wanted, you could, in theory, operate a centrally planned economy successfully. It has never happened. Because man is an ornery fellow, prone to putting a stick in the economists’ wheels. Not that he is malicious or obstructionist. It’s just that he and only he really knows what he wants; and he changes his mind often.

The Economy of Stuff

Ultimately, economics is about material wealth. It’s about stuff. Economists’ conceit is that they can help people get more of it, that they can bring the average man more wealth, by improving the unemployment rate or boosting the GDP growth rate or increasing some other fraudulent number they created with one of their prize-winning theories. With more stuff, they contend, the average man will be better off.

But stuff doesn’t automatically have a fixed value. What is yesterday’s newspaper worth? How about a painting? Or an ounce of gold? Or a pound of frogs’ legs?

The value of Stuff is established by people. They declare their interest in stuff by bidding for it in the market. Thus do they set the price for a loaf of bread, a share of Google, or an hour of someone’s time. Markets are not perfect. They never “know” what the price should be. And they are subject to fits of panic, disgust, greed, and infatuation, just like the individuals who participate in them.

The market gods play tricks…they set traps…they toy with us…they seek to ruin us…and they discover exactly the right price—set by willing buyers and sellers—every day.

In financial terms, the market ‘clears’ when buyers and sellers figure out the price that will get the deal done. Then, they can regret it later.

The price is essential. It is what tells farmers they overplanted or homebuyers that they have waited too long. It’s what causes speculators to look for open windows and investors to postpone retirement. It is what tells the producer what he should have produced and the consumer what he wished he could consume. It’s what tells you what people really want.

Since real wealth can only be measured in terms of what people really want, any distortion of prices is misleading, vain, and potentially impoverishing. Bend prices and you send producers off in the wrong direction, making stuff that people don’t really want. Everyone is poorer as a result. Even the smallest amount of central planning, where it disturbs private, individual planning to the slightest effect, reduces the sum of human happiness.

Taxes, tariffs, import restrictions, quotas, subsidies, bailouts, product specifications—every meddle is a fat thumb on the market scales. The price data is corrupted. The producer doesn’t know what the consumer wants. The consumers’ choices are sub-optimal. The whole economy is hobbled. Everyone gets less of the stuff he really wants and more of the stuff he doesn’t.

If you agree with that, guess what…you’re going against an entire century of economic theory and practice. The modern economist believes he can improve the way people invest, save, spend and do business. In the United States he has been hard at it—manipulating, interfering, controlling—for a century, at least since the Federal Reserve system was founded in 1913. Is there any evidence that all this sweat and heavy breathing has actually worked? That it has actually improved the way economies function? None that we have seen. But now after 100 years of meddling, economics itself is sinking below the zero barrier, down into dark under world of hormegeddon, where the return on further effort will be starkly, catastrophically negative.


Bill Bonner is an American author of books and articles on economic and financial subjects, the founder and president of Agora Publishing, co-founder and regular contributor to The Daily Reckoning, and author of a daily financial column, Diary of a Rogue Economist. 

He is author and co-author of Financial Reckoning Day: Surviving The Soft Depression of The 21st Century, Empire of Debt and Mobs, Messiahs and Markets.

Click here to order Bill Bonner’s forthcoming book: Hormegeddon: How Too Much of a Good Thing Leads to Disaster.

This excerpt first appeared at the Casey Daily Despatch. Part Two will appear here tomorrow …

Wednesday, 22 May 2013

Maturing with H.L. Mencken

Look in any good dictionary of quotes, and after Shakespeare and Oscar Wilde you’re likely to find one H.L. Mencken coming in third for the number of quotes included. Samples: “Democracy is the theory that the common people know what they want, and deserve to get it good and hard” “Puritanism: the haunting fear that someone, somewhere is having a good time” – “The whole aim of practical politics is to keep the populace alarmed (and hence clamorous to be led to safety) by menacing it with an endless series of hobgoblins, all of them imaginary.”
Guest poster Bill Bonner argues there are more reasons to read Mencken than just his undeniable pith.

The writings of Henri Louis Mencken — the Sage of Baltimore — one of the most influential American writers of pithy prose  -- have been a constant companion for me since the start of my writing life. The brilliance, the language, the insight, the derring-do opinionating, the history, the astounding literacy — it’s all here, and it all flows seemingly without limit. All these features are combined in one mind and life, yet none of these features is the reason why it is important to read Mencken. The most important reason is that Mencken assists in the great struggle to free yourself from intellectual conventions and become a mature observer of the world.

To mature means to gradually let go of dependence on others and to depend on your own resources. It also means to accept responsibility for the judgments you make, and not slough them off on other people. It is the same with thinking. To mature means to break loose from canned forms of thought that you once accepted without question, and instead see the world for what it is. It is the essential step toward living a free life.

imageModern democracy seems to war against this kind of maturation. Take a look at the best-selling political and financial books on the conventional lists. Their goal is to play to your biases, to bring you the comfort of having something you already think reinforced. In politics, it means cheering for party X over party Y on grounds that you accept ideology X over ideology Y. There simply is no large market for people who accept some of each or reject both.

In finance, it means believing that the world is either progressively coming together or falling apart. The evidence to support this either/or proposition is assembled in order to confirm as true what you would otherwise think.

This is the easy path. But it is not obtaining maturity. It is not thinking for yourself. It is dependence. It consists in shaping your thinking to a model forged by others. People who read only this way imagine that they are educating themselves. Actually, they are only gorging themselves on settled conventions.

If we really want to think hard and maturely, we need to encounter ideas that cause some element of discomfort. We need to leave our comfort zones and imagine that perhaps the mob is not as smart as people say. Maybe we can only find the truth of a situation in an opinion that cuts against the grain, is not represented by political party, and departs radically from settled orthodoxies. When we realize this, we enter on the road to intellectual maturity.

The thinkers and writers who can assist in this process are few. When they do appear, they disappear just as quickly for lack of champions. I fear this might be the fate of H.L. Mencken. For decades, he was there to stir the pot and work against mob opinion. This is why he opposed U.S. entry into World War I. This is why he was a literary progressive in times when most people were stuck in the past. This is why he ridiculed Prohibition when the entire Northeast religious and government establishment thought it was a brilliant idea. This is why he never shrank from flailing orthodoxies that were accepted by nearly everyone.

Throughout his career, as soon as he found a solid bloc of champions, he would lose them just as quickly. He was uncomfortable with popularity, assuming it was a sign that he needed to shake things up a bit. For example, by the late 1920s, he was the darling of the literati and the toast of the town. His attacks on the Hoover administration kept him in good graces, but then he turned his eye toward Franklin Roosevelt and ridiculed the New Deal for the monstrosity that it was. His support peeled away, and he once again found himself alone. He further dissented on the second charge for war in his lifetime and permanently fell out of favour.

Mencken was a champion of the individual, of rationality, of the human mind, in a century of collectivism of every sort. This is why he seriously doubted that individualism could triumph in an era of mass political and religious manias. As his American Credo showed, he understood American culture as few others before or since have. He loved America and its multifarious cultures, but he also saw that there was an intractable problem that would prevent America from ever achieving its hope. That flaw he summed up with the word “puritanism.” He was referring not so much to a narrow religious sect, but to an outlook on life that sought the destruction of sin and imperfection and, in so doing, warred against human volition and freedom itself.

Mencken never sought to bring comfort to his readers. He sought to disturb and dislodge biases, pointing to uncomfortable truths about the world around us. In this sense, he was one of the few truly independent thinkers of the last century. He left a mighty legacy that allows us to study under him — not so much the specifics of what he said, but rather how he thought. Everyone who seeks to live a freer, happier, and more prosperous life can now look to him as an example of what it means to exercise truly independent thinking. To be his student means to be grounded even as those around you are being buffeted about by the winds of public opinion and political manipulation.

It’s all summed up in the revolutionary idea of Mencken’s core credo: “I believe that it is better to tell the truth than a lie. I believe it is better to be free than to be a slave. And I believe it is better to know than to be ignorant.”

Sincerely,
Bill Bonner

Bill Bonner is the founder and president of Agora Publishing, and the principal author of The Daily Reckoning.
He is the co-author of the books Financial Reckoning Day: Surviving The Soft Depression of The 21st Century, Empire of Debt, and Mobs, Messiahs and Markets.
This article first appeared at Laissez Faire Today .

Tuesday, 11 May 2010

Greece is the word [update 2]

Greece is “rescued.” One trillion dollars worth of paper. “Europe’s TARP”… and we all saw how well that worked. 

The billion-dollar bailout (a seven-fold increase in just one day) is the signal sign that at the heart of the Euro experiment is the morality of welfare economics that’s dragging down country after country: a system that turns one nation’s “need” into an international claim—that makes resort to inflation “easy, smooth, and above all respectable.” A system promising that those who’ve been profligate will always be able to send the bill for their blow-outs to those who haven’t been; and that to “defend” that currency the strong will always have to stand ready to bail out the weak.

It’s the morality of sacrifice turned into international economics.

Seeking sanity amid the flags and banners of approval at this latest paper shower propping up all the bad positions (which explains in itself most of the cheering from those being propped up), I offer you what sanity I found midst the dross:

_quote Once again the vast majority fails to see a crisis in the making, even as it stares at them from close range. Just as market observers in 2007 told us that the credit crisis would be confined to the subprime mortgage market, current analysts tell us that sovereign debt problems are confined to Greece, Spain, Portugal, and perhaps Italy. They were wrong then, and I believe that they're wrong now.”
            - Peter Schiff, quoted at The Rational Capitalist:
              “Schiff: Is Sovereign Debt Crisis Contained to Subprime?

_quote Basically the European Central Bank is monetizing bad government debt claims.
         - Tyler Cowen, writing at Marginal Revolution:
          “Simple thoughts on Europe

_quote As we see the market rally this morning on news of the near-trillion dollar European bailout, we should keep this point in mind.  What's good for capitalists is often NOT what's good for capitalism, not to mention the long-term well-being of most of the citizenry…
    “The desire for ‘stability’ is indeed the siren's song of the end of freedom.”
            - Steven Horvitz, writing at The Coordination Problem:
              “The "Siren's Song of Stability," European Version

_quote  At a cost of [one-trillion dollars], Europe will pretend to protect Greece from its creditors and the Hellenes will pretend to put their financial affairs in order. Instead, the Greek affair will slide into a larger crisis. As we explained last week, all of modern macro-finance can be understood as an attempt to push problems into the future and onto people who were not to blame for causing them. Now we see the formula at work in Europe.”
            - Bill Bonner, writing at The Daily Reckoning:
              “Say You Want a Revolution?

_quote Notice also that the capital that is used to provide the bailout goes from the hands of savers into the hands of bondholders who made bad investments. We are not only allocating global savings to governments. We are further allocating global savings precisely to those who were the worst stewards of the world's capital.”
            - John Hussmann, linked at Mish’s blog:
              “Greek Debt and Backward Induction

_quote The European Central Bank has flunked the first major test of its independence and its commitment to the single goal of low inflation. It announced yesterday, in so many words, that it will print as much money as it takes to keep prices up and yields low on government bonds issued by Eurozone governments… 
    “This is a solvency crisis, not a liquidity crisis. Eurozone government bond yields have risen not in a scramble for liquidity (base money), but with an upward revision in estimates of default risk. Monetary expansion treats the debt problem only by inflating away the value of the euro.
    “’We are going to defend the euro, [Spanish Finance Minister Elena] Salgado told reporters…  Defending the euro is in fact the opposite of what the ECB has announced it will do. Salgado is not telling the truth. Either she know she is lying, or Europe's fiscal authorities really don't understand. If the ECB is now following the lead of the fiscal authorities, neither of the two possibilities bodes well for the euro.”
            - Larry White, writing at Division of Labor:
               “The value of European government debt is not the value of the Euro

_quote This is a whole new level of global moral hazard - the result of an alliance of convenience between troubled governments in the south of Europe and the north European banks (and implicitly, north American banks) who enabled their debt habit.”
            - Peter Boone & Simon Johnson, writing at The Baseline Scenario:
              “Eurozone: The Kitchen Sink Goes In – Now It’s All About Solvency

_quote Contagion, or contagion theory, is sweeping the euro zone, where Greece’s debt crisis is infecting neighboring countries and threatening to make its way across the Atlantic to U.S. shores.
    “At least that’s what we’re told on a daily basis…
    “I hate to pour cold water on that theory, but healthy countries aren’t susceptible to Greece’s disease…
    “On the other hand, it would be a mistake to interpret the flight-to-quality into U.S. Treasuries last week as a sign of immunity. The U.S. is already infected with the debt virus. It’s still in its incubation period.”
            - Caroline Baum, linked at Mish’s Blog:
              “Greek Contagion Myth Masks Real Europe Crisis

_quote Being Keynesians, the majority of economists primarily only consider aggregate demand/consumption to discern the economy's condition, rarely parsing the relative contributions of the private and public sectors and the sources of growth of consumption, and most always with the assumption that incremental government borrowing and spending will pass through or kick start and sustain private economic activity for the cycle.
    “But when private debt growth and associated increasing returns to financial capital have been the primary source of growth since the early '80s to early to mid-'70s, increasing government borrowing and spending to make up for the loss of debt growth in the private sector only results in government debt eventually growing faster than exponential vs. incomes, production, and GDP, setting the stage for fiscal insolvency atop private sector debt-deflation…”
            - “My Friend BC,” quoted at Mish’s Blog.

_quoteI own the Euro, I hope it rallies. There are gigantic short positions in the Euro, but I would have said that a week ago too and it went down. In the end, I don`t think the Euro will survive, 10 years, 15 years from now. But at the moment it will probably have a rally"
             - Jim Rogers in Bloomberg, May 10

_quote German Chancellor Angela Merkel says this action was necessary to fight a Euro short selling syndicate. ]The eurozone's member states showed yesterday that we have a common political will to do everything for the stability of our common currency,’ she said. ‘This is a determined and united message to those who think that they can weaken Europe.’
    ”I have news for the Chancellor: you are merely building a bigger problem that ultimately will result in a bigger failure.”
            - Bill Cara, writing at his blog

_quoteWhat seems to escape every one of these fatuous macromancers is that, for years now, Greece has been the very essence of Keynesian folly: that the heavy hand of the state, by distributing a corrupting largesse derived from the government-supported evil of fractional reserve banking and constituted of laughably mispriced, fiat-money lending, had so successfully ’stimulated’ the country and artificially boosted the shibboleth of its GDP that it is now reduced to a state of penury so extreme — and is plagued with a false sense of entitlement so engrained — that all conceivable solutions to its woes now seem like bad ones.”
            - Sean Corrigan, linked at The Cobden Report:
              “Greece has been the very essence of Keynesian folly

_quoteThe Wall Street Journal reports on the issue, noting that American taxpayers [and NZ taxpayers!] will be involuntary participants thanks to the financial world’s keystone cops at the International Monetary Fund.”
           - Daniel J. Mitchell, writing at the Cato Blog:
             “Europe’s Über Bailout

_quoteA German reporter with a very poor, or very excellent, sense of humour has been handing out the old Greek currency (Drachma) to Greeks on the streets of Athens, just to record their reaction. He obviously didn't expect to get the worthless paper torn from his hands – literally.”
            - Nickolai Hubble writing at The Daily Reckoning:
              “Chaos No Longer a Theory

_quoteAs the crisis continues in Europe, one aspect remains unmentioned: Why are the Germans the focus of the debate?
    “The answer is of course that they are the Eurozone's centre of growth, stability and fiscal responsibility. Sadly, they gave up their role as the monetary standard of Europe with the Euro. Still, it is the Germans that the world is looking to when it comes to Europe's fiscal crisis.
    “But how did this come to be? Less than a lifetime ago, Germany was little more than a mound of rubble with some metal scraps mixed in…”
            Read on here for the only good-news economics story you’re likely to hear today . . .

UPDATE 1: Who’s been living beyond their means, then?  Here’s a good wee picture of the world’s government debt bubble. It’s easy to see that the counties living most beyond their means are those who’ve been most devoted to the (Keynesian) welfare economics that’s now destroying them.  The colour gives the the debt of the country’s government as a percentage of GDP (i.e., their ability to pay it back); the size shows the absolute size of that debt (i.e., how much everyone else stands to lose when they don’t). Just take a look at the size of Europe.  And Britain…

6a00d83451591e69e20133ec99d4c8970b 

PS: The tat tip for the map goes to what looks like a surprisingly economic literate British MP, a chap called Steven Baker.

UPDATE 2: Matt Nolan corrects my prose with a point he earlier made here:

    “[The picture] is only telling us government debt as a % of GDP I believe - weirdly, overseas they often called public debt national debt. If we took private + public debt NZ would look a lot bigger ;-)
    “And if we looked at the more important net private+public debt (so taking away assets) NZ looks very ... special.”

I don’t think he means “special” in a good way.